When a contingent pay scheme is used salary is habitually formed by two
components: a fixed element, usually known as base pay, and an additional,
variable component which is usually provided in the form of one or more lump
sums.
As a general rule, the practice of consolidating variable pay into base
pay should preferably be avoided in that this method risks making it even more
difficult for employers achieving their business objectives. Once this approach
is used, individuals might lose sight of the link existing between this
component of pay and their performance, would take thus this payment for
granted and no longer as an addition which needs to be re-earned every year.
Putting aside any consideration about the motivating effectiveness of
variable pay, it is absolutely normal that individuals may behave differently
according to the circumstance that a component of their financial reward is
variable or otherwise. Whether this originally flexible component of pay would
be converted into a firm part of salary, there would not in fact be any particular
apparent need for individuals to go the extra mile. In such a circumstance,
employees should possibly find the reasons for performing at their best everywhere
but in the variable component of pay.
The actual payment of the variable component of pay should rather be invariably,
directly linked to the achievement of a particular personal or group objective agreed
at the beginning of each year between employees and their Line Managers. Albeit
directly linking the attainment of a pre-set objective to the payment of a
variable component of pay might produce no effects at all in terms of
motivation, this should if anything help managers to have specifically
important works properly done.
A relatively recent survey, carried out amongst more than 500 employers
in the US by Aon Hewitt, revealed that three-quarters of businesses expect to
reach, or even exceed, business performance expectations, which accounts for pay
and variable pay budgets to remain stable in 2011. Just a few companies
anticipated the implementation of drastic pay freeze policies in order to reduce
the personnel budget. The research also shows that nearly two-thirds of
employers did not change their original base salary increase budgets, confirming
that base salary increases, stabilising at sub-3 percent, will not return to
pre-recession levels anytime soon.
Variable pay, accounting for 11.6 percent (and just a measly -0.02
percent compared to 2010) of salaried exempt workers’ payroll (that is, workers
for whom overtime rules do not apply) seems to be, by contrast, destined to
firmly holding on in 2011.
Ken Abosch, development leader in Aon Hewitt's Broad-Based Compensation
Consulting Practice, said that the findings of the investigation suggests that,
downturn notwithstanding, employers have invested in variable pay during the
last three years as they have never done before. With the aim of rewarding
staff in order to encourage strong individual and business performance, organizations
are also likely to continue having recourse to reward management approaches
based on variable pay also in the future. The main objective of such a choice seems
to be fairly clear; employers want their employees to know that they are
willing to provide them extra cash, provided that these effectively contribute
to the organisation’s achievement of strong results.
In
order to effectively implement contingent pay schemes, employers should first
and foremost identify which factors they intend to link to the payment of the
variable component of salary: performance, contribution, skills, results,
competence or whatever else. Once these factors have been clearly identified,
employers should determine the method to measure and assess these KPIs, safe in
the knowledge that the more objective the method selected is, the fairer the
rewarding approach will be perceived to be by individuals.
The measurement and assessment of the factors identified can hence be expressed by ratings, which by means of a formula enable employers to calculate the amount that has to be paid to the employees. Employers could also decide to determine the payments on the basis of a broader assessment method, rather than by mathematics formulae, but in this case the method could be prone to be deemed subject to bias and subjective, rather than objective, appreciation.
The measurement and assessment of the factors identified can hence be expressed by ratings, which by means of a formula enable employers to calculate the amount that has to be paid to the employees. Employers could also decide to determine the payments on the basis of a broader assessment method, rather than by mathematics formulae, but in this case the method could be prone to be deemed subject to bias and subjective, rather than objective, appreciation.
According to Brown (2011), there are basically two main reasons for
variability being considered so important by employers in the current economic
landscape. One of them is essentially represented by the flexibility it allows
businesses in terms of rewarding policies. Reducing in fact the base pay
component of reward, employers will be in the position to control the personnel
budget when the organisational performance drops without any need to resort to jobs
cut. In contrast, employees will be able to cash in on financial gains during prosperity
periods.
The second reason for employers preferring having recourse to variable
pay programmes is linked to their concern for retaining and motivating high
fliers, especially when they are experiencing difficult times. By means of
variable pay schemes they can redirect more of their pay and bonus budget in
order to ensure these individuals are constantly properly remunerated.
The
fact that variable pay and incentives might be considered an effective
long-term motivator can be indeed considered questionable at best. Although it
cannot be excluded that variable pay can have some positive motivating effects
in the short run, it is nowadays rather widely recognised that extrinsic
motivators cannot produce valuable effects to this extent. It is just for this
reason in fact that organisations are shifting their approach towards total
reward models which, by means of the intrinsic/non-financial motivator component
these entail, are likely to produce more effectual long-lasting motivational
effects (Total reward – What should be considered before addressing the issue).
Considering the motivational effects of contingent pay, as warned by
Armstrong (2006), a distinction needs to be made between financial incentives
and financial rewards.
Financial incentives - aiming at making aware individuals of the money
they will receive in the future whether they perform well, are considered as direct
motivators. These are essentially granted on the basis of the hypothetical promise
“Do this and you will get that”. Sales incentives are a typical example of
financial incentives.
Financial rewards – in contrast, representing a
tangible recognition of specific achievements, are considered indirect
motivators. As showed by the expectancy theory, individuals feel motivated
whether they expect that what they attain in the future produces valuable results
which are as such appreciated and valued by the others.
Financial rewards can both be prospective and retrospective. Prospective
reward is to some extent based on gambling, the employer feels that since an
employee has already reached an appreciable level of competencies and skills this
will surely perform well in the future. Although the money the employer invests
(or bets) on an individual is, in this case, partly justified by the level of
competencies this has gained, it is nonetheless impossible to predict today how
the individual will actually perform in determined situations in the future,
especially whether the employer has never had the opportunity to practically
test how the individual typically behaves in those circumstances or in that
particular role. The move could even result counterproductive in the event,
against all expectations, things should not work as planned, rewards would not
be repeated, that is to say paid again, and this will clearly produce
detrimental effects on the employee motivation.
People are usually prone to quickly forget the rewards they have
received at earlier stages and are, in any case, expected to receive something
more immediately after having yielded a good result. This is another reason for
the prospective approach to financial reward being likely to fail producing the
desired results in the short term too.
Retrospective reward is actually the most widely used method to provide
staff financial recognition. It is based on the real situation “You have
attained this result; hence we pay you this sum of money.”
Considering
the benefits of the short term momentum that financial reward can provide, a
mix of prospective and retrospective reward could reveal to be particularly
appropriate and effective when appointing individuals for some complex projects
or assignments, especially for those requiring some extra efforts during the
pre-implementation phase. Providing individuals a lump sum at the start of the
project or assignment and one soon after the successful conclusion of it is
likely to be particularly appreciated by the individuals concerned.
Organisations whose culture, values and shared beliefs are inspired by productivity, performance, contribution and the recognition of the actual achievement of these, will find this method particularly useful to inspire integrity and effectively and consistently foster and consolidate their values and beliefs.
If the worst comes to the worst, the introduction of variable pay
schemes based on real contribution and performance can produce somewhat of a natural
process by means of which organisations can achieve a better labour
distribution and allocation amongst their staff. Individuals who are able and
willing to perform at higher standard levels are stimulated to move ahead in
higher level jobs where they take growing degrees of responsibility on and provide
superior contribution whilst being better rewarded. Vice versa, those employees
whose level of performance is poor continue to fill lower profile, low-paid
roles. In order to prevent this circumstance to clearly emerge, these
individuals may very likely decide opting for alternative jobs and hence
leaving the organization. All of that should consequently lead to improve the
final quality of the overall output produced by the different organizational divisions.
Supporters of the expectancy theory are amongst those who consider
incentives schemes useful to increase organisational performance and
productivity. They believe that inasmuch as individuals are keen to produce more
and better whether they are aware that other people value their achievements, individuals
are also expected to receive in turn something they value. This position, nevertheless,
is questionable at best in that it takes for granted that all the individuals
invariably and equally value and appreciate extrinsic rewards, which as we will
see later, is not actually true and cannot hence be taken as axiomatic.
In reality, the introduction of incentive payment systems in any
organisations is not widely recognised as useful and as having positive impact
on the organisation’s productivity and performance. According to Sisson and
Storey (2000), for instance, many organisations have developed incentive
schemes just for “ideological reasons”, that is, to impress stock markets
analysts, reinforcing the role played by the organisation’s management and to
void the role played by trade unions in the salary determination process. Albeit,
they conclude, more often than not these reasons reveal to be completely
ineffective in the long run.
Contingent pay programmes, especially individual incentive schemes, are not
really immune from criticism. Contingent pay has attracted widespread criticism
over time; one of the most relevant is certainly represented by the
considerably limited impact individual contingent pay is expected to make on employee
motivation. In general, financial rewards are in fact deemed to only produce a
partial influence on employee motivation. These can help to avoid that things
could go any worse, rather than prompting individuals to go the extra mile or induce
discretionary behaviour (Herzberg, 1957). Whether managed inappropriately, pay
can even act as a demotivating factor. Kohn (1993) suggests that money seldom
enable employers to effectively influence their staff behaviour. Another
criticism to incentives schemes is raised by Thompson (2000) who warns against the
employee perception of incentive schemes as a further management control tool
used to the detriment of individual autonomy and causing as such resentment and
industrial conflicts.
Moreover, since individuals are different one another and differently react
to the diverse ways they can be motivated, it cannot be taken as axiomatic that
all individuals will be equally motivated by tangible rewards and let alone by
the same type of reward. This is actually one of the main reasons for Total
Reward approaches being considered of remarkable importance.
Individuals who are just motivated by financial rewards and who are thus
expected to receive money in exchange for their performance will surely react
positively to financial incentives. Fully complying with these extrinsic staff
expectations, nonetheless, employers risk undermining the significance of intrinsic
motivation; with the passing of time individuals motivated just by money could
find it unpleasant to deal with their daily tasks and activities (Armstrong,
2006) and could therefore be destined to underperform. Additionally, employers
supporting this employees’ attitude may to some degree contribute to abet these
in this approach. Whether staff is used to receive money for everything they
do, considering they work in an organisation to actually do something valuable
and receive an annual pay for this, the result could be that in order to
motivate staff employers should rise the worthiness of the incentives they
offer at an increasing frequency, widening rather than bridging the reward gap
with other employees with different attitudes but equal (or even superior) performance.
In the mid-run, the risk is that everybody in the organisation may develop the
same attitude towards financial incentives, which could ultimately undermine
the stability of the whole organisation even in periods dominated by favourable
economic conditions, not to mention the catastrophic effects such practice may
lead to during downturn or grim financial periods.
Such schemes definitely “cause considerable additional costs”
(Torrington, 2008) and as suggested by Cox (2006) are very likely to generate
“costly side-effects.”
It is also extremely important to become aware of the likely effects an
incentive scheme can produce according to the different areas and situations;
as suggested by Torrington (2008), “there is a world of difference” between a
system rewarding an additional 3 percent and one rewarding an additional 25
percent. An investigation carried out in the United States by Bartol and Durham
(2000), for instance, revealed that the minimum salary increase capable to
elicit positive long-term response has to be set between 5 percent and 7
percent of the current salary. A similar study carried out in Finland
(Piekkola, 2005) revealed that beneficial effects on staff productivity can be generated
by a 3.6 percent salary increase. The obvious conclusion of these
investigations is that employers’ efforts will not produce any effect at all
whether individual expectations are not adequately met.
These investigations could also partially explain the difficulties faced
by public sector employers in motivating their staff, since they usually
recognise incentives between 2 percent and 3 percent of current salary (Hendry
et al., 2000).
Clearly these indications also need to be considered in respect of the
times, in period of downturn or in a post-recession period where employees
could consider themselves somewhat of blessed for having being able to keep
their jobs, salary increases could be appreciated differently than it would be
during periods in which the sun is shining.
Whether variable financial rewards can contribute to foster competition
and enhance productivity and performance, the backlashes these may produce could
reveal at times to be particularly detrimental for organisations. Financial incentives
may possibly motivate some individuals, but could produce counterproductive demotivating
effects on those individuals who do not expect further sum of money to perform
well. In the latter case, financial incentives are even likely to cause
counterproductive reactions, weakening and distracting individuals’ attention from
the intrinsic benefits these receive whilst performing their tasks (Armstrong,
2006). In number the latter are likely to be more numerous than the former so
that the negative impact on the overall organisation climate and performance
could be particularly considerable.
In order to properly work, it is also mandatory that contingent pay
schemes are based on accurate and reliable methods effectively and consistently
enabling organisations to assess and measure performance and staff contribution
to organisational success; methods which not always exist or are operated effectively.
The introduction of individual contingent pay schemes seriously risks jeopardising
the efforts of modern organisations to implement organisational structures and
working methods the more and more based on team and group working. Individuals
who want to appear particularly brilliant, also to show their employer that
they deserve the extra money they receive, could be tempted to work in
isolation if not to be unfair or disloyal with the other team members, to the
detriment of the final overall results that the organisation is expected to
attain by the work produced by the whole team. This is possibly why team-based
incentives are seen by some practitioners much better than the individual ones
(Pfeffer, 1998 and Torrington, 2008).
Contingent pay
schemes are all too often destined to fail because of the difficulties related
to their effective and consistent management and implementation processes. Investigations
carried out by Bowey (1982), Kessler and Purcell (1992), Marsden and Richardson
(1994) and Thompson (1992) have all revealed that the reasons for failure are
usually due to bad and ineffective implementation and to the lack of line managers’
preparation and capacity.
Line managers
are of paramount importance for the implementation of every organisation’s
strategy and policy and clearly contingent pay and incentives schemes,
especially when implemented by means of performance management systems, make no
exception.
In order to
effectively work contingent pay schemes need the total support of LMs, who need
to genuinely believe in the contribution of contingent pay to their
organisation success. Line managers “can make or break contingent pay schemes”
(Armstrong, 2006), so that they need to effectively contribute to their direct
reports target determination and to the consistent and fair measurement and
assessment of their staff performance.
LMs should also
find the time, usually reported as one of the more recurrent reasons for
managers actually not doing it, to communicate and provide feedback to their
direct reports on the way the organisation’s performance management process works
and on the influence it eventually has on their pay.
Finally, it can
be said that as typical of many HR- and management-related issues, contingent
pay programmes cannot be effectively managed resorting to the one-size-fits-all
approach, their success or failure is in fact sorely depending on the different
situations and contexts in which these are developed and implemented. This is also
what actually emerged from the findings of a thorough investigation carried out
by Brown and Armstrong (1999), which come to two conclusions: contingent pay
cannot “be endorsed or rejected universally as a principle” and “no type of
contingent pay is universally successful or unsuccessful.”
The study also
confirmed that many organisations have experienced a lot of problems and
difficulties, from the practical point of view, when implementing contingent
pay systems.
Some studies (Huselid
1995; Lazear 2000; Piekkola 2005 and Gielen et al. 2006) let it transpire a
correlation between incentives systems and performance, whereas others (Pearce
et al 1985 and Thompson 1992) have revealed no objective evidence of any
interrelation. Corby et al (2005) claim that although several investigations
show the existence of a correlation between organisational performance and
incentives schemes, there is indeed no evidence of a causal relationship between
the two. Basically, also these studies and investigations come to the same
conclusion as that cited above: the success or failure of the schemes essentially
depend on the circumstances.
It
can therefore be concluded with Torrington et al (2008) that failure is
inevitable when the wrong scheme is applied to the wrong people, in the wrong
circumstances or for the wrong reasons.
Longo, R., (2011), Pros and cons of variable pay and incentives,
HR Professionals, [online].
For
an extended version of this article and much, much more click here